Lecture 3
Contrary to theoretical accounts that suggest that institutional complementarities support stability and institutional reproduction, the authors argue that the linkages across these realms have helped to translate employer strategies that originated in the realm of industrial relations into a stable, new, and less egalitarian model with state support.
Centralized collective bargaining firm-based bargaining.
Labor markets: not solely deregulated, but the number of “atypical” or “nonstandard” employment relationships + working poor – risen sharply in recent years.
Significant changes high degree of formal institutional stability
Focus of the article: 3 institutional arenas (industrial relations, labor markets, and social protection) in the political economies of Germany and France.
Some authors: see it as liberalization and a move toward the American model.
This article’ argument: politics and the outcomes institutionalization of new forms of dualism (less harsh than the American model but also distinctly less egalitarian than before).
Cross-class coalitions European countries not succumbing to liberalization, but also helping to promote dualization.
France & Germany:
actors in the “core” economy well-positioned to defend traditional institutions and practices for themselves, but no longer serving as leaders;
able to resist outright liberalization, but especially vulnerable to dualization
More recent work on “dualization”: macro-political perspective.
The theory by David Rueda:
labor market insiders and outsiders have distinct (and in many ways contradictory) preferences with respect to labor market policy;
insiders: preferring strong employment protections over more flexibility to ease the reentry of outsiders into the labor market;
outsiders: preferring the opposite;
social-democratic governments interests of insiders over those of outsiders;
corporatist arrangements: do not stimulate social democrats to bring the interests of outsiders on board;
social democracy: not a problem (as Rueda argues) but a part of the solution (to resist dualism);
dualist trends: far more pronounced in the continental European countries than in the Nordic countries, where social democratic parties are stronger and in some cases near hegemonic;
political coalitions labor market policy, industrial relations, social protection;
institutionalization of dualism changes in industrial relations, labor market policy, and welfare state reforms.
Theoretical lenses: political economy institutional complementarities.
Core industrial sectors “standard employment relationships”:
Germany: large export firms in manufacturing (e.g., automobiles and machine tools);
France: nationalized firms like Renault + large public enterprises such as EDF (electricity) or SNCF (railways)
Manufacturing industry unions from the public sector state policies diffusion, generalization, and institutionalization (almost) the whole population: directly for male wage earners and indirectly for their families.
Popular opinion: connections across related institutional domains stabilizing force.
Reason: reformers in one area will have to consider as well the costs of possible “collateral damage” to complementary institutions.
However, reverse effect is possible: changes in one area destabilize relations in others.
More consistent with Germany and France: tight coupling among institutional realms reforms in adjoining policy arenas as well.
Germany and France: responses to the economic crisis of the 1970s and 1980s organized around saving the core manufacturing economy:
reducing the size of the workforce employed in the industrial sectors (extensive use of early retirement);
increasing the productivity among remaining workers through increased internal flexibility and intensification of work;
negotiating new kinds of company-based deals with the remaining workforce that traded job security against increased productivity.
Collateral damage:
robbing the core industry of its ability to serve as lead for the rest of the economy;
new types of jobs on the outside secondary labor market for nonstandard employment relationships;
state institutionalization of these new types of employment: more flexibility, less security;
“exceptional” employment growing not allowed to compete with the core sector (i.e., putting so much pressure on it as to compromise wages and security there);
growth of the secondary labor market financial and political pressure for the development of a secondary type of welfare protection;
traditionally segregated risk pools:
financed by social contributions paid by employees and employers (payroll and not general taxes)
past contributions eligibility for benefits
increase in unemployment and in the number of jobs that are (partially) exempted from contributions
system not designed to finance the social protection of those who did not participate in the “normal” economy and contribute to the social insurance funds
undermining financial basis of the traditional regime
welfare reforms: sharpening the line between social insurance (for those who had paid their social contributions) and social assistance + in-work benefits for those excluded from the normal labor market and for whom the state was asked to take responsibility.
Germany:
organization rate: 35 % in the 1970s below 25 % today;
labor movement: relatively centralized, featuring a few noncompeting multi-industrial unions;
coordination: manufacturing sector. High levels of employer organization pattern bargaining led informally by the powerful Metalworkers Union (IG Metall) 1970-80s: corporatist models like those of Scandinavia.
France:
organization rate: 20 % in 1955 < 10 % currently;
labor movement: fragmented along ideological lines;
coordination: nationalized companies sector- or national-level agreements all firms active within the industry or the country, even if they are signed by only a minority of the trade unions and employers’ associations
Both countries: very high levels of collective bargaining coverage (at around 80 %) high degree of national-level harmonization of working conditions and wages.
However, since 1980s: shrinkage in the traditional “core” “inward turn” on the part of firms and sectors that once led the economy.
Germany:
decline of employment in manufacturing union density among the actively employed: 32.7 % in 1980 21.7 % in 2004;
membership in German unions & employer associations employment structures of 1960s, with strongholds in manufacturing and low representation in services
France:
decline of employment in industrial sector: 25 % in 1978 14 % in 2006;
leading public companies (unions’ stronghold): privatized from mid-1980s and increasingly after 1993;
unionization: 17 % 8 %; same composition: membership rates 3 times higher in big companies (public or private) than in small ones and 2~3 times higher in industry than in the service sectors (including services to industry)
First oil crisis protecting core skilled workers.
“Inward turn” decentralized negotiations.
Germany:
1972 Revised Works Constitution Act empowered works councils in their negotiations with management, but enhanced their autonomy vis-à-vis the overarching industrial unions;
1995: position of Metal Employers’ Association (Gesamtmetall) collapsed when plant managers proved unwilling to disrupt relations with their local works councils, refusing to heed the association’s call for a lockout;
2003: works councils in the West unwilling to continue striking for gains that would redound to the benefit of workers in the East.
France:
Auroux Laws of 1983: government’s idea to strengthen unions by anchoring their position in firms;
result: wounding up weakening unions by giving unorganized groups a boost;
wave of privatizations was explicitly relieving large, former state-owned enterprises from their public responsibilities.
Statutory minimum wage in Germany (€ 9.82):
supported by:
German Food and Restaurant Workers’ Union (NGG) – representing poorly organized workers with low skills
2004 Germany’s new (and more encompassing) United Service Sector Union (ver.di)
opposed by:
manufacturing unions – enjoying considerable market power. Fearing it would compromise bargaining autonomy and put downward pressure on wages in their sectors.
main employer confederations, the German Employers’ Association (BDA), and the Confederation of German Industries (BDI).
In France (€ 9.67):
relatively high statutory wage; preventing strong wage dispersion among regular full-time employees;
previous (Fordist) model: every job linked to a coefficient included in salary scales; negotiated by unions and employers at the sectorial level;
1980s onward: range of wages increased as firms added different bonuses to a basic wage;
divide between workers:
large firms:
smaller firms: outsourcing, atypical working contracts, protection and working conditions deteriorated
1993-2000 laws on working-time reduction:
large industrial firms and the public sector – unions maintaining a presence. Trading working-time flexibility and increased productivity for job security;
small firms and low-skill service sectors: working arrangements and conditions deteriorated and external flexibility has increased;
high-skill and white-collar workers: working-time reduction improvements in work and life quality;
lower paid and less skilled workers: income losses, more variable schedules, and intensified work.
Germany and France – industrial restructuring in the 1980s and 1990s:
reducing the size of the workforce and increasing the productivity of the remaining workers increasing competitiveness of core sectors by reducing the size of the workforce and increasing the productivity of the remaining workers;
massive use of early retirement stabilizing the remaining jobs that became harder and more flexible than before;
rather than conflict between labor and capital, intensification of cooperation between managers and workers in leading firms (Germany’s manufacturing sector and in France’s large companies);
exacerbated coordination at higher levels;
reason: unanticipated working out of developments in collective bargaining, some of which had been designed to empower organized labor;
structures put in place in the 1970s and early 1980s to enhance labor’s voice at the plant level fueling trends toward dualism when economic hard times hit
Labor market reforms – not affecting the status of core workers.
Germany:
legal stipulations; provisions in collective contracts protecting older workers and employees with long tenure;
large and well-unionized companies: strong works councils with significant rights in the area of plant personnel policy;
mid-1980s: increase in “atypical” jobs;
late 1990s: numbers have increased steadily, even as their pay and benefits have declined relative to “regular” employees;
reforms in the 1980s and 1990s:
agency workers: 3 months in 1972 12 months by 1997 unlimited in 2003;
fixed-term contracts: 1985 & 1996 reforms – up to 2 years without special justification;
growth in atypical employment (primarily: mini-jobs):
previously occupied by students, housewives, and others who did not rely on such jobs as primary sources of income or benefits;
traditionally exempt from all contributions up to a threshold of earnings (in 1998 the limit was DM630);
employees paid no payroll taxes at all;
employers could pass their taxes on to the workers, who in many cases were tax exempt;
non-wage labor costs grew in the 1980s and 1990s employers found this arrangement increasingly attractive number of such jobs increased well beyond the originally intended clientele
1999 reform (not welcomed by employers):
2002 reform (welcomed by employers):
Mini-jobs: 2 million in 1991 4.7 million in 2005. + 1.7 million mini-jobs as secondary employment (thanks to the 2002 legislation).
Gender component: new possibilities for women to enter the labor market.
However: conflicts of interest among women who participate in the labor market for different reasons and on different terms:
single-mother mini-jobbers in Germany:
welcoming regularization of benefits
incentives for working in mini-jobs (being contribution-free on the worker side) often yielding higher take-home pay than regular part-time work
fearing wage increases taking them above the upper earnings limit attached to mini-jobs push them into an employment zone (subject to contributions) drastically reducing their take-home pay
women who already enjoy benefits through their insider husbands and are simply supplementing family income:
France:
1988 Mitterand reelection: reinstated protections for regular workers;
1993: required social plans to contain detailed provisions concerning the workers to be dismissed;
shrinking core outsourcing of certain functions to smaller firms that could make use of more flexible forms of employment;
expansion of services (construction, restaurants, goods delivery, child care, elderly care) rise of a secondary labor market “non-standard” work contracts and lower standards (for pay, working conditions, and social protection);
trade unions: successfully resisted major changes in employment protection for core workers, but experienced growing pressure to accept increased flexibility for other types of jobs.
Atypical jobs (fixed-term, part-time, and agency jobs): 3 % in 1970 25 % by 2007. Currently, 70 % of the new job contracts are currently “atypical”.
1986: enabling firms to hire temporary workers for their normal activities + extending the maximum term to 2 years.
1990-2000s: creation of subsidized, fixed-term, low-paid jobs for low-skilled workers. Peaked in 2005 at around 500,000.
Official goal: enabling the unskilled young and long-term unemployed to remain in the mainstream of society by providing a minimum income in exchange for some kind of activity, be it work or training.
1990 – 2000:
short-term employment grew by 60 %;
trainees, recipients of special contracts via public financing: + 65 %;
temporary employment grew by 130 %;
regular employment increased by only 2 %
Unions tend to support the protection of the core and flexibilization of the periphery dual reform
Women:
1970s and 1980s: increasing numbers of inactive workers supported by fewer active workers driving up non-wage labor costs (to more than 40 % of gross wages) and dampening job creation.
Core problem: growing number of workers making less contributions, drawing out of more from the system
Occupational insurance/contributory benefits nonoccupational/noncontributory benefits (taken care by the state)
France:
1984: those with the shortest contribution records are excluded from any entitlement to unemployment insurance benefits pressing social problem
1988: RMI (Revenu Minimum d’Insertion):
1992: AUD (Allocation Unique Dégressive):
Germany:
1990s: social insurance system became untenable:
From 1998 onward:
Harz IV:
Regional dimension (disadvantaged East vis-à-vis West):
France & Germany:
Differences with a would-be typical neoliberal deregulation:
If you see mistakes or want to suggest changes, please create an issue on the source repository.
Text and figures are licensed under Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 4.0. Source code is available at https://github.com/ko-suta/labor-dualism-tuebingen, unless otherwise noted. The figures that have been reused from other sources don't fall under this license and can be recognized by a note in their caption: "Figure from ...".