Coordination as a political problem

Lecture 2

Thelen, K., & Kume, I. (2006). Coordination as a political problem in coordinated market economies. Governance, 19 (1), 11-42.

Gist

Purpose: to examine the differences in how employer coordination has been organized in Sweden, Germany, and Japan in the area of industrial relations.

Argument: intensification of cooperation between labor and management in some firms and industries has paradoxically had deeply destabilizing collateral effects that have undermined these systems as they were traditionally constituted.

Background

Recent Varieties of Capitalism (VoC): industrial relations depend not only upon labor organization and strength, but also on the coordination between employers.

Coordinated market economies (CMEs):

Liberal market economies (LMEs):

Some argue that globalization and deregulation will lead to convergence – all capitalist systems will become liberal.

VoC opinion:

Basic logic: employers have organized their competitive strategies around these institutions will not abandon them in the face of new market pressures.

Challenges to the VoC framework

Do institutions really resist deregulation thanks to employers’ genuine interest?

Alternative explanations:

Significant tensions in Sweden, Germany (declining union membership) and Japan (departure from seniority wages and lifetime employment). Thus, not only “coordination”, but also struggles matter.

Contemporary market conditions:

Intensification of cooperation between labor and management in some firms and industries (that the VoC literature correctly emphasizes) has paradoxically deep destabilizing collateral effects.

Germany

Background: organizational disarray in the Association of German Metalworking firms (Gesamtmetall) and its union counterpart (IG Metall), which together have played the key flagship role in Germany’s de facto system of pattern bargaining over most of the postwar period.

Firms calling for greater flexibility to adapt central bargains to the needs of individual firms.

1960s: collective bargaining was covering 80% of all firms accounting for 90% of all workers.

Union organization in Germany: around 30% of all workers throughout the postwar period vs. Swedish unions’ 80%.

However, German employers have traditionally been extremely well-organized contracts signed by the employer associations cover all workers in the member firms, regardless of their status as union members or not stabilized encompassing bargaining

Large export firms sizable sector of small and medium-sized firms (Mittelstand):

Some of the most destabilizing trends: intensified cooperation between labor and capital at the plant level (especially in larger firms).

Clear tensions since 1980s: negotiations over working hours’ reduction (down to 35):

Subsequent collective bargaining rounds in the 1990s exacerbated problems of solidarity on the employer side.

German producers: facing much stiffer competition from high-quality (lower-cost) producers in Japan and elsewhere. Late 1990s: bargaining rounds that featured remarkable displays of disunity on the part of metalworking employers (that became risk-averse).

Weaker firms: opting out of the industry-level contract altogether shrinking number of firms participating in central bargaining.

Union leaders’ ability to conclude binding and encompassing agreements continued organizational viability of employers. Unions’ achievements were muted, frequently accompanied by expressions of concern about the weakness of employers’ association.

Lack of unity and discord: prominent features of the IG Metall’s internal politics at present.

In 2003, the IG Metall strike (over reducing the working time in East Germany from 38 to 35 hours, as in the West) failed for the first time since 1950s.

Employers such as Gesamtmetall’s head Kannegiesser explicitly defend the collective bargaining system for the “order” and “predictability” that it helps to impose on the labor market.

Japan

Postwar system of “lifetime employment” (shūshin koyō) + seniority wages (nenkō joretsu): incentive mechanisms for workers.

Japanese management practices operate on a firm level (rather than on industrial, as in Germany).

Importance of coordination (rather than competition) between employers.

Lifetime employment only works if workers start at low wages, and then gradually acquire skills that make them increasingly productive and valuable to the company.

Management-labor coordination is less formal than in Germany. Conducted via the seasonal Shuntō wage bargaining system.

Since 1960s: the metal industry had become the main pattern-setting industry. Unions, organized in the IMF-JC (International Metal Workers’ Federation Japan Council), have traditionally demanded “economically rational” wage increases.

Recent years: intensified questioning of the traditional wage system. Employer organizations such as Keidanren (Federation of Economic Organizations) and Nikkeiren have criticized seniority wages as rigid and harmful for Japanese firms. Reasons:

  1. Demographic change (aging workforce) has increased the number of older workers, and with that, increased also the total wage costs that firms must bear.

  2. Seniority wage system change: came closer to an automatic wage raise for many workers despite different job capabilities among workers of the same age.

  3. “IT revolution”: changed the kinds of skills that firms need. Traditional on-the-job training over a worker’s career may be less attractive than hiring engineers with the relevant skills from outside the company.

Thus, many companies have moved to abolish the seniority wage system, often replacing this with performance-based wages (seikashugi).

However, as in Germany, one finds in Japan evidence of continued employer support for both lifetime employment practices and substantial aspects of traditional wage systems. 1995 Nikkeiren report “A Japanese Management System in the New Era”. Urging firms to distinguish among three different types of workers:

Toyota management:

Toyota chairman Hiroshi Okuda in 1999:

“Even if there are redundant workers, it is management’s responsibility to seek new business opportunities to redeploy them. Employers without the entrepreneurship to find such business opportunities should retire.”

The chairman of the board of Fujitsu concurred with Okuda, citing his company’s successful efforts to retain workers through retraining and redeployment. Fujitsu management: it is important to evaluate workers’ potential ability and “work process” independently of “outcome”.

On contrary, pioneer of the performance-based system, Takeda Chemical (the largest pharmaceutical company in Japan), found it difficult to keep employees committed to the company.

1990s: Takeda Chemical and Mitsui Mining and Smelting adopted performance-based wages, leaving the Shuntō framework altogether.

The major problem: how to make individualistic wages compatible with the group-oriented work organization of Japanese firms.

Nissan case:

However, not all companies can accomplish this same balance (traditional employment practices + fine-tuning wage systems).

New divide among core firms in the Japanese economy:

Increasing adoption of performance-based wage systems difficult to maintain the traditional Shuntō system:

Sweden

Background

High level of centralization.

1956-1983: broad wage settlements blue-collar union confederation Landorganisationen (LO) National Confederation of Swedish Employers (SAF).

1980-90s: collapse of the system, as SAF eliminated its own bargaining unit.

However, from 1990s on: re-equilibration of wage bargaining instead of decentralization.

Currently: highly coordinated bargaining across industries within the export sector. Much stronger cooperation than ever before between blue-collar unions and white-collar workers.

However: much looser coordination between the exposed and sheltered sectors of the economy.

growing wage differentiation within and especially between these broad bargaining clusters significant compression of wages across the economy.

The case

Swedish employers: originally agreed to centralized bargaining ensuring wage moderation. However, over time wage settlements became rigid and highly inflationary.

Before 1960s: centralized bargaining wage solidarism equalizing pay across industries and plants (“equal pay for equal work” regardless of a firm’s profitability) shift in resources (including labor) out of declining and into more competitive industries.

From late 1960s: wage solidarity took an egalitarian turn compressing relative wages across the board.

compensating low-paid groups (public sector and low-skilled industrial workers) for wage drift enjoyed by skilled industrial workers chronic, institutionalized ratcheting up of wages.

1980s and 1990s: negative effects felt especially in the engineering industry employer association in that sector (Verkstadsföreningen, or VF; later Verstadsindustrier, or VI) led the drive for bargaining decentralization.

VF/VI opposed the new wage-leveling clauses no resonance among employers in other industries that were less affected 1983: VI withdrew from traditional bargaining altogether separate deal with the metalworkers’ union, Metall decisive blow to the traditional nationally-coordinated system.

Employers in the engineering industry led the charge against the old system. Rather than “neoliberal employer offensive” against the traditional Swedish system, cross-class realignment bringing together employers and unions in the export sectors (especially in the engineering industry), at the expense of traditional, more encompassing forms of coordination and solidarity.

1983: initial break with centralized bargaining – not through conflict, but through a deal. VF offered the metalworkers’ union (Metall) a wage increase above what the union had demanded decoupling negotiations from the peak bargain and eliminating contractual provisions that compressed the wages of skilled and unskilled workers.

Engineering workers – thinking of public-sector workers as “pay parasites” resented their ability to free-ride on the productivity gains in engineering through the compensation clauses.

Furthermore, interoccupational leveling clauses (between skilled and unskilled workers) – a problem for Metall. Technological changes in engineering blurring the line between skilled blue-collar and white-collar occupations high-skill metalworkers working in jobs similar to that of members of the separate white-collar union, Svenska Industritjänstemannaförbundet (SIF). But, wage compression within Metall receiving much lower wages than white-collar workers.

VI’s break with the system uncertainty demands from firms like Volvo, Ericsson, and ABB for further decentralization to the plant level.

Plus, SAF dismantling of its own bargaining apparatus in 1990. Employers continued to oppose any recentralization of national bargaining under the auspices of the LO and SAF.

But, other firms and sectors advocating for more intermediate solution of industry-level negotiations both full decentralization to the plant level and return to national-level bargaining are impossible.

1995 bargaining round:

1996: Metall joined with its white-collar counterpart (SIF) and other unions in export sectors invited other employers to engage in joint negotiations over wage formation.

1997: 8 unions and 12 employer associations new “Agreement on Industrial Development and Wage Formation”:

2000: a new national Mediation Authority (Medlingsinstitutet) was established, replacing the old, weaker National Conciliator’s Office:

Summary

Employer coordination has proved more resilient than adherents to a strict neoliberal offensive thesis might have predicted.

Full decentralization to the plant level (as advocated in the 1980s and 1990s by prominent firms such as ABB, Volvo, and Ericsson) has been averted, and there is significant coordination across the industry sector as a whole.

Confederal level (with white- and blue-collar workers negotiating separately) coordination across the blue-/ white-collar divide and across export industries.

Since 1990s: union alliances based upon class increasingly replaced by constellations based upon sector.

Renegotiation of the terms of coordination:

  1. Confederal bargaining industry-level bargaining: employers sloughed off several layers of coordination dragging on their ability to restructure production and to maneuver effectively in increasingly competitive international markets.

VI’s initial withdrawal from peak negotiations blow to solidaristic wage bargaining as traditionally practiced in Sweden.

Not that much neoliberal offensive by employers against labor, but the intensified cooperation between labor and capital in the metalworking industry at the expense of solidarity and coordination across sectors.

  1. Relinking metal industry to other export industries, thus bringing back coordination organized around what the industry sector as a whole can bear.

Significant shift:

Conclusion

Recent market developments intensification of cooperation between labor and management weakening traditional forms of coordination among employers, undermining solidarity among workers and the system of institutional coordination.

Common trends:

Corrections

If you see mistakes or want to suggest changes, please create an issue on the source repository.

Reuse

Text and figures are licensed under Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 4.0. Source code is available at https://github.com/ko-suta/labor-dualism-tuebingen, unless otherwise noted. The figures that have been reused from other sources don't fall under this license and can be recognized by a note in their caption: "Figure from ...".